MillenniumPost
Opinion

Better laws for a better future

Land leasing laws relating to rural agricultural land in Indian states were overwhelmingly enacted during decades immediately following the Independence. At the time, the abolition of the Zamindari system and redistribution of land to the tiller were the highest priorities for policy-making.

Top leadership of the day saw tenancy and sub-tenancy as integral to the feudal land arrangements that India had inherited from the British. Therefore, tenancy reform laws that various states adopted sought to not only transfer ownership rights to the tenant but also either prohibited or heavily discouraged leasing and sub-leasing of land.

In trying to force the transfer of ownership to the cultivator, many states abolished tenancy altogether. But while resulting in minimal land transfer, the policy had the unintended consequence of ending any protection tenants might have had, and forced future tenants underground.

Some states allowed tenancy but imposed a ceiling on land rent at one-fourth to one-fifth of the produce. But since this rent fell well below the market rate, contracts became oral in these states as well, with the tenant paying closer to 50 per cent of the produce in rent.

The original intent of the restrictive tenancy laws no longer holds any relevance. Today, these restrictions have detrimental effects on not only the tenant for whose protection the laws were originally enacted but also on the landowner and implementation of public policy. The tenant lacks the security of tenure that they would have if laws permitted them and the landowner to freely write transparent contracts.

In turn, this discourages them from making long-term investments in land and also leaves them feeling perpetually insecure about continuing to maintain cultivation rights. Furthermore, it deprives them of potential access to credit by virtue of being a cultivator.

Landowner also feels some insecurity when leasing land with many choosing to leave land fallow. The latter practice is becoming increasingly prevalent with landowners and their children seeking non-farm occupations.

Public policy too faces serious challenges today in the absence of transparent land leasing laws. There are calls for expanded and more effective crop insurance. Recognising that such insurance is likely to be highly subsidised, as has been the case with the past programmes, a natural question is how to ensure that the tenant who bears the bulk of the risk of cultivation receives this benefit.The same problem arises in the face of a natural calamity; if tenancy is informal, how do we ensure that the actual cultivator receives disaster relief.

In a similar vein, fertiliser subsidy today is subject to vast leakages and sales of subsidised fertiliser in the black market. In principle, these leakages could be sharply curtailed by the introduction of direct benefit transfer (DBT) using Aadhar seeded bank accounts along the lines of the cooking gas subsidy transfer. But in face of difficulty in identifying the real cultivator and therefore intended beneficiary, DBT cannot be satisfactorily implemented.

In the context of the difficulties in land acquisition under the 2013 land acquisition law, states wishing to facilitate industrialisation can further benefit from liberal land leasing if they simultaneously liberalise the use of agricultural land for non-agricultural purposes.

Currently, conversion of agricultural land for non-agricultural use requires permission from the appropriate authority, which can take a long time. State governments can address this barrier by either an amendment of the law to permit non-agricultural use or by the introduction of time-bound clearances of applications for the conversion of agricultural land use in the implementing regulations.
The reform opens up another avenue to the provision of land for industrialisation: long-term land leases that allow the owner to retain the ownership while earning rent on her land. In addition, they will have the right to renegotiate the terms of the lease once the existing lease expires.

Therefore, the introduction of transparent land leasing laws that allow the potential tenant or sharecropper to engage in written contracts with the landowner is a win-win reform. The tenant will have an incentive to make investment in improvement of land, landowner will be able to lease land without fear of losing it to the tenant and the government will be able to implement its policies efficiently.

Simultaneous liberalisation of land use laws will also open up an alternative avenue to the provision of land for industrialisation that is fully within the state’s jurisdiction and allows the landowner to retain ownership of their land.

A potential hurdle to the land leasing reform laws is that landowners may fear that a future populist 
government may use the written tenancy contracts as the basis of transfer of land to the tenant and therefore would oppose the reform. This is a genuine fear but may be addressed in two alternative ways.

The ideal way would be yet another major reform: giving landowners indefeasible titles. States such as Karnataka that have fully digitised land records and the registration system are indeed in a position to move in this direction. For other states, such titles are a futuristic solution.Therefore, in the interim, they can opt for the alternative solution of recording the contracts at the level of the Panchayat eschewing acknowledging the tenant in the revenue records. They may then insert in the relevant implementing regulations the clause that for purposes of ownership transfer, only the tenancy status in revenue records would be recognised.

State governments must seriously consider revisiting their leasing (and land use) laws to determine if they could bring about these simple but powerful changes to enhance productivity and welfare all around. We, at the NITI Aayog, stand ready to assist them in this endeavour.

(The writer is Vice Chairman, NITI Aayog) 

Next Story
Share it